California Agriculture
California Agriculture
California Agriculture
University of California
California Agriculture

All Issues

Sidebar: Hot-button issues for Endangered Species Act reauthorization

Share using any of the popular social networks Share by sending an email Print article
Share using any of the popular social networks Share by sending an email Print article

Authors

Patrick Y. O'Brien, Chevron Research and Technology Company, Richmond

Publication Information

California Agriculture 49(6):35-37. https://doi.org/10.3733/ca.v049n06p35

Published November 01, 1995

PDF  |  Citation  |  Permissions

Author Affiliations show

Abstract

Abstract Not Available – First paragraph follows: The Endangered Species Act (ESA) establishes protection of threatened and endangered species as a national goal. However, human use of land and water often conflicts with the habitat needs of other species, which means that protective measures can interfere with economic development and other socially beneficial public works projects. This is the basic friction point that sparks most of the issues included in the debate over reauthorizing the ESA.

Full text

The Endangered Species Act (ESA) establishes protection of threatened and endangered species as a national goal. However, human use of land and water often conflicts with the habitat needs of other species, which means that protective measures can interfere with economic development and other socially beneficial public works projects. This is the basic friction point that sparks most of the issues included in the debate over reauthorizing the ESA.

Twenty-two years after its passage in 1973, the ESA is under heavy attack and its future is uncertain. More than ever before, Congress is inclined to revamp the ESA, especially to relieve burdens on private landowners. In contrast, the ESA's defenders feel that many of the proposed reforms will increase the likelihood of species' extinction. Although the ESA imposes stringent mandates on public agencies as well as on private parties, environmentalists feel that it should be strengthened because humans are placing increasing stress on ecosystems that support endangered species. A variety of measures, some already embraced in policies adopted by Secretary of Interior Bruce Babbitt to defuse the mounting pressure for reform, could make the ESA more palatable to private landowners, while retaining its basic protective structure and features.

The ESA was originally inspired by population declines in a number of species with popular appeal such as the bald eagle, the peregrine falcon, the grizzly bear and the timber wolf. Despite public surveys which show that most Americans support the ESA's goals, many people view the law itself as inflexible, unfair to private landowners, unresponsive to certain social and economic factors, marginally successful, and a surrogate for other agendas. These arguments have all been made before, but last fall the public signaled a change in sentiment by electing legislators who were receptive to them.

Conflicts have arisen over protection of habitat for endangered species including the salt marsh harvest mouse.

Conflicts have arisen over protection of habitat for endangered species including the salt marsh harvest mouse.

One controversial aspect of the ESA is that in addition to protecting the highly visible species that appeal to the public, the Act also protects relatively obscure species. When the presence of an obscure species restricts the use of land or water, it creates controversy. Examples abound: in California alone, the Delta smelt has disrupted water deliveries to Central Valley agriculture; the Stephens and Tipton kangaroo rats have restricted cultivation practices in Southern California and the San Joaquin Valley, respectively; the California gnatcatcher has created tremendous uncertainty over the future of real estate development in coastal southern counties; and the northern spotted owl has dampened timber harvesting in the north.

Another controversial aspect of the ESA is that it allows the listing of plant and animal subspecies as well as of distinct population segments of vertebrate animals. This aspect has allowed for protection of the bald eagle, southern sea otter, timber wolf and grizzly bear in the lower 48 states even though healthy populations of the same species exist in Canada and Alaska. In addition, scientists disagree about whether some groups of animals, such as the California gnatcatcher and Alabama sturgeon, should qualify as subspecies and therefore be accorded legal protection. Subspecies definitions are often subjective because there is little scientific consensus about what criteria should be applied to what taxonomic groupings.

Some ESA critics want to protect most plants and animals only at the species level, partly because it is difficult to identify subspecies and we lack sufficient data to understand their contribution to genetic variability in most cases. Many scientists counter that protecting subspecies is very likely to increase a species' genetic variability, thus fostering its adaptive potential and survival. They feel that methods for identifying distinct groupings should be improved to make this practice more reliable and credible.

ESA reformists also criticize another aspect of its implementation: disproportionately heavy expenditures on a relatively few species. The single species emphasis has probably been needed to save the California condor, whooping crane, black-footed ferret, Puerto Rican parrot, and Florida panther, whose numbers are still dangerously low. But ESA defenders and critics generally agree that management plans focusing on individual species are inadequate. Multispecies or ecosystem-level planning would reduce the need for individual species listings, which produce added layers of regulatory complexity. However, due to their different objectives, ESA defenders and reformists will undoubtedly push for different mechanisms to implement multispecies plans.

Another point of contention is whether or not to consider the cost-effectiveness of protecting species. Recent court settlements have required the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service to accelerate its schedule for making decisions about listing several hundred high priority candidate species. This faster listing pace has intensified pressure to justify the cost-effectiveness of species protections. Environmentalists feel that cost-benefit analysis would put species at a major disadvantage because their intangible value has already been heavily discounted in the face of economic growth, and that making further tradeoffs would aggravate extinction risk.

The ESA requires federal agencies to ensure that actions they fund, authorize, or carry out are not likely to jeopardize threatened or endangered species, or their critical habitat. Critical habitat is considered those specific areas containing the physical and biological features essential for the conservation of the species. This “non-jeopardy” requirement is under siege by those who think that federal agencies should have more discretion to balance conservation objectives with their other responsibilities such as regulating timber harvests, generating electric power, and distributing water. Environmentalists fear that compromising the non-jeopardy requirement will create irreparable tears in the safety net the ESA affords for imperiled species.

Finally and perhaps most importantly, Congress will have to determine whether and how to regulate habitat on private lands. This comes about because Section 9 of the ESA prohibits “take” of endangered species and by regulation, threatened species. The ban on species take does not distinguish between public and private lands. Most of the unlawful actions included under the definition of “take” cause direct injury or mortality such as hunting, shooting, wounding, killing, capturing and so on. However, “take” also covers “harm” which has been interpreted in regulation to include disturbance of habitat that kills or injures wildlife by significantly impairing essential behavior patterns such as breeding, feeding or sheltering. Last summer the Supreme Court affirmed this interpretation in its decision on Sweet Home Chapter v. Babbitt, which challenged the regulatory definition of harm.

While it is clear that conserving species depends on protecting their habitat, many advocates of private landowner rights view the protection of habitat on private land as excessive intrusion by the federal government. In a move widely hailed by ESA reformists, the House of Representatives recently passed a bill that would require compensation for landowners who suffer greater than 20% loss of property value due to government regulations. The Senate has not yet taken action on this measure.

Because so many species needing protection occur on private lands, new approaches are urgently needed to encourage cooperation among landowners. Secretary of Interior Babbitt has recently tried to show the ESA can be flexible enough to allay at least some landowners concerns. His “no surprises” and small landowner exemption policies attempt to ease the regulated community's fears about the barriers created when a listed species is found in the path of a development project. “No surprises” aims to assure landowners that conservation planning efforts that consider unlisted candidate species will not be invalidated if these species are later listed. Proposed federal rules would also create an exemption from the taking ban on threatened species for certain small projects. Reformists say that these policies are a good start but that they need to go further and be memorialized in legislation. Some environmentalists view these initiatives as helpful to resolving ESA conflicts while others feel they are useless attempts to appease landowners in the face of political pressure.

In addition, many feel that the current law creates perverse incentives for landowners to eliminate habitat out of fear that threatened and endangered species will occur on their property. This is clearly counterproductive and needs to be outweighed by incentives to protect habitat. Ways of easing the burden on private landowners and of increasing their confidence in the ESA include:

  • Encouraging voluntary conservation management agreements such as tax benefits for committing land to conservation.

  • Providing “safe harbor” exemptions when listed species colonize protected habitat.

  • Offering habitat credit trading systems that enable habitat units to be readily bought and sold in order to facilitate both mitigation and conservation objectives.

  • Writing restrictions that can be relaxed when local conservation planning goals are met.

  • Tailoring “take” rules to specific land use activities such as oil well drilling, plugging and abandonment operations.

  • Authorizing general permits for certain categories of ongoing operations and maintenance activities such as right of way or fire safety clearances that have minimal adverse effects.

  • Providing public funding for habitat conservation planning efforts.

  • Passing an amendment to the ESA that memorializes the “no surprises” policy and extends it by stipulating that no newly listed species will invalidate existing conservation agreements.

  • Expediting small project permits by amending the Section 10(a) incidental take permit process to eliminate Environmental Assessments, internal Section 7 consultations and multiple levels of administrative review for small projects that do not trigger interagency consultations.

  • Stressing and including greater landowner participation in recovery programs.

The above actions would also reduce the need to compensate landowners for economic loss, also a necessary feature of ESA administration, but preferably the one of last resort.

Return to top

Sidebar: Hot-button issues for Endangered Species Act reauthorization

Patrick Y. O'Brien
Webmaster Email: sjosterman@ucanr.edu

Sidebar: Hot-button issues for Endangered Species Act reauthorization

Share using any of the popular social networks Share by sending an email Print article
Share using any of the popular social networks Share by sending an email Print article

Authors

Patrick Y. O'Brien, Chevron Research and Technology Company, Richmond

Publication Information

California Agriculture 49(6):35-37. https://doi.org/10.3733/ca.v049n06p35

Published November 01, 1995

PDF  |  Citation  |  Permissions

Author Affiliations show

Abstract

Abstract Not Available – First paragraph follows: The Endangered Species Act (ESA) establishes protection of threatened and endangered species as a national goal. However, human use of land and water often conflicts with the habitat needs of other species, which means that protective measures can interfere with economic development and other socially beneficial public works projects. This is the basic friction point that sparks most of the issues included in the debate over reauthorizing the ESA.

Full text

The Endangered Species Act (ESA) establishes protection of threatened and endangered species as a national goal. However, human use of land and water often conflicts with the habitat needs of other species, which means that protective measures can interfere with economic development and other socially beneficial public works projects. This is the basic friction point that sparks most of the issues included in the debate over reauthorizing the ESA.

Twenty-two years after its passage in 1973, the ESA is under heavy attack and its future is uncertain. More than ever before, Congress is inclined to revamp the ESA, especially to relieve burdens on private landowners. In contrast, the ESA's defenders feel that many of the proposed reforms will increase the likelihood of species' extinction. Although the ESA imposes stringent mandates on public agencies as well as on private parties, environmentalists feel that it should be strengthened because humans are placing increasing stress on ecosystems that support endangered species. A variety of measures, some already embraced in policies adopted by Secretary of Interior Bruce Babbitt to defuse the mounting pressure for reform, could make the ESA more palatable to private landowners, while retaining its basic protective structure and features.

The ESA was originally inspired by population declines in a number of species with popular appeal such as the bald eagle, the peregrine falcon, the grizzly bear and the timber wolf. Despite public surveys which show that most Americans support the ESA's goals, many people view the law itself as inflexible, unfair to private landowners, unresponsive to certain social and economic factors, marginally successful, and a surrogate for other agendas. These arguments have all been made before, but last fall the public signaled a change in sentiment by electing legislators who were receptive to them.

Conflicts have arisen over protection of habitat for endangered species including the salt marsh harvest mouse.

Conflicts have arisen over protection of habitat for endangered species including the salt marsh harvest mouse.

One controversial aspect of the ESA is that in addition to protecting the highly visible species that appeal to the public, the Act also protects relatively obscure species. When the presence of an obscure species restricts the use of land or water, it creates controversy. Examples abound: in California alone, the Delta smelt has disrupted water deliveries to Central Valley agriculture; the Stephens and Tipton kangaroo rats have restricted cultivation practices in Southern California and the San Joaquin Valley, respectively; the California gnatcatcher has created tremendous uncertainty over the future of real estate development in coastal southern counties; and the northern spotted owl has dampened timber harvesting in the north.

Another controversial aspect of the ESA is that it allows the listing of plant and animal subspecies as well as of distinct population segments of vertebrate animals. This aspect has allowed for protection of the bald eagle, southern sea otter, timber wolf and grizzly bear in the lower 48 states even though healthy populations of the same species exist in Canada and Alaska. In addition, scientists disagree about whether some groups of animals, such as the California gnatcatcher and Alabama sturgeon, should qualify as subspecies and therefore be accorded legal protection. Subspecies definitions are often subjective because there is little scientific consensus about what criteria should be applied to what taxonomic groupings.

Some ESA critics want to protect most plants and animals only at the species level, partly because it is difficult to identify subspecies and we lack sufficient data to understand their contribution to genetic variability in most cases. Many scientists counter that protecting subspecies is very likely to increase a species' genetic variability, thus fostering its adaptive potential and survival. They feel that methods for identifying distinct groupings should be improved to make this practice more reliable and credible.

ESA reformists also criticize another aspect of its implementation: disproportionately heavy expenditures on a relatively few species. The single species emphasis has probably been needed to save the California condor, whooping crane, black-footed ferret, Puerto Rican parrot, and Florida panther, whose numbers are still dangerously low. But ESA defenders and critics generally agree that management plans focusing on individual species are inadequate. Multispecies or ecosystem-level planning would reduce the need for individual species listings, which produce added layers of regulatory complexity. However, due to their different objectives, ESA defenders and reformists will undoubtedly push for different mechanisms to implement multispecies plans.

Another point of contention is whether or not to consider the cost-effectiveness of protecting species. Recent court settlements have required the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service to accelerate its schedule for making decisions about listing several hundred high priority candidate species. This faster listing pace has intensified pressure to justify the cost-effectiveness of species protections. Environmentalists feel that cost-benefit analysis would put species at a major disadvantage because their intangible value has already been heavily discounted in the face of economic growth, and that making further tradeoffs would aggravate extinction risk.

The ESA requires federal agencies to ensure that actions they fund, authorize, or carry out are not likely to jeopardize threatened or endangered species, or their critical habitat. Critical habitat is considered those specific areas containing the physical and biological features essential for the conservation of the species. This “non-jeopardy” requirement is under siege by those who think that federal agencies should have more discretion to balance conservation objectives with their other responsibilities such as regulating timber harvests, generating electric power, and distributing water. Environmentalists fear that compromising the non-jeopardy requirement will create irreparable tears in the safety net the ESA affords for imperiled species.

Finally and perhaps most importantly, Congress will have to determine whether and how to regulate habitat on private lands. This comes about because Section 9 of the ESA prohibits “take” of endangered species and by regulation, threatened species. The ban on species take does not distinguish between public and private lands. Most of the unlawful actions included under the definition of “take” cause direct injury or mortality such as hunting, shooting, wounding, killing, capturing and so on. However, “take” also covers “harm” which has been interpreted in regulation to include disturbance of habitat that kills or injures wildlife by significantly impairing essential behavior patterns such as breeding, feeding or sheltering. Last summer the Supreme Court affirmed this interpretation in its decision on Sweet Home Chapter v. Babbitt, which challenged the regulatory definition of harm.

While it is clear that conserving species depends on protecting their habitat, many advocates of private landowner rights view the protection of habitat on private land as excessive intrusion by the federal government. In a move widely hailed by ESA reformists, the House of Representatives recently passed a bill that would require compensation for landowners who suffer greater than 20% loss of property value due to government regulations. The Senate has not yet taken action on this measure.

Because so many species needing protection occur on private lands, new approaches are urgently needed to encourage cooperation among landowners. Secretary of Interior Babbitt has recently tried to show the ESA can be flexible enough to allay at least some landowners concerns. His “no surprises” and small landowner exemption policies attempt to ease the regulated community's fears about the barriers created when a listed species is found in the path of a development project. “No surprises” aims to assure landowners that conservation planning efforts that consider unlisted candidate species will not be invalidated if these species are later listed. Proposed federal rules would also create an exemption from the taking ban on threatened species for certain small projects. Reformists say that these policies are a good start but that they need to go further and be memorialized in legislation. Some environmentalists view these initiatives as helpful to resolving ESA conflicts while others feel they are useless attempts to appease landowners in the face of political pressure.

In addition, many feel that the current law creates perverse incentives for landowners to eliminate habitat out of fear that threatened and endangered species will occur on their property. This is clearly counterproductive and needs to be outweighed by incentives to protect habitat. Ways of easing the burden on private landowners and of increasing their confidence in the ESA include:

  • Encouraging voluntary conservation management agreements such as tax benefits for committing land to conservation.

  • Providing “safe harbor” exemptions when listed species colonize protected habitat.

  • Offering habitat credit trading systems that enable habitat units to be readily bought and sold in order to facilitate both mitigation and conservation objectives.

  • Writing restrictions that can be relaxed when local conservation planning goals are met.

  • Tailoring “take” rules to specific land use activities such as oil well drilling, plugging and abandonment operations.

  • Authorizing general permits for certain categories of ongoing operations and maintenance activities such as right of way or fire safety clearances that have minimal adverse effects.

  • Providing public funding for habitat conservation planning efforts.

  • Passing an amendment to the ESA that memorializes the “no surprises” policy and extends it by stipulating that no newly listed species will invalidate existing conservation agreements.

  • Expediting small project permits by amending the Section 10(a) incidental take permit process to eliminate Environmental Assessments, internal Section 7 consultations and multiple levels of administrative review for small projects that do not trigger interagency consultations.

  • Stressing and including greater landowner participation in recovery programs.

The above actions would also reduce the need to compensate landowners for economic loss, also a necessary feature of ESA administration, but preferably the one of last resort.

Return to top


University of California, 2801 Second Street, Room 184, Davis, CA, 95618
Email: calag@ucanr.edu | Phone: (530) 750-1223 | Fax: (510) 665-3427
Website: https://calag.ucanr.edu